Los administradores de TransicionEstructural no se responsabilizan de las opiniones vertidas por los usuarios del foro. Cada usuario asume la responsabilidad de los comentarios publicados.
0 Usuarios y 4 Visitantes están viendo este tema.
[...]En el primer gráfico parece referirse a "la pública + la priva menos sector financiero* "* vaya por Dios jeje ese sector siempre va "aparte"
El reciente informe Deleveraging?, What deleveraging?, publicado por Geneva Reports on the World Economy, aporta una visión internacional comparada de esa dinámica de endeudamiento.Lo cierto es que la deuda mundial ha continuado creciendo desde el inicio de la crisis y loha hecho, fundamentalmente, por la posición de los países emergentes. Dentro del bloque desarrollado, las divergencias son relevantes, tanto en lo que respecta a la evolución del volumen agregado de deuda como al comportamiento por sectores institucionales. De acuerdo con el mencionado Informe Geneva de 2014, la deuda agregada de las economías desarrolladas, excluyendo la contraída por el sector financiero, ha pasado de cotas del 230% del PIB en 2007 al 272% en 2013, presentando EE.UU., Reino Unido y la eurozona ratios y evoluciones similares. El aumento de la ratio agregada en los últimos seis años convive con la caída o estabilización del endeudamiento privado y el repunte de la deuda pública.[A. Bergés y Sara Baliña, 'El mapa de la deuda en España' Cuadernos de Información Económica Funcas, AFI]
Gracias! Sí, tal y como yo lo entiendo (corrígeme si me equivoco) el pasivo del sector financiero no lo agregan porque, si yo le presto a un banco, y el banco le presta a Juanito el frutero de la esquina, estaríamos contabilizando dos veces la deuda dentro del propio país......aunque lo que no acabo de entender es que, si yo le presto al Santander y el Santander aprovecha esos recursos para dar más préstamos en, por ejemplo, Brasil, ¿qué "doble contabilidad" estaríamos evitando en ese caso?
Is Volkswagen About To Unleash The Next Deflationary Wave?http://www.zerohedge.com/news/2015-09-23/volkswagen-about-unleash-next-deflationary-wave
We're gonna need a German bailout... or more chemical plant explosions...
HONG KONG – In the wake of a global stock-market sell-off triggered by economic turmoil in China, the US Federal Reserve has just decided to postpone raising interest rates. Indeed, China is facing the huge challenge of dealing with the risk of a global debt-deflation trap.In 1933, Irving Fisher was the first to identify the dangers of over-indebtedness and deflation, demonstrating their contribution to the Great Depression in the United States. Forty years later, Charles Kindleberger applied the theory in a global context, emphasizing the problems that arise in a world lacking coordinated and consistent monetary, fiscal, and regulatory policies, as well as an international lender of last resort. In 2011, Richard Koo used Japan’s experience to highlight the risks of a prolonged balance-sheet recession, when over-stretched debtors deleverage in order to rebuild their balance sheets.The debt-deflation cycle begins with an imbalance or displacement, which fuels excessive exuberance, over-borrowing, and speculative trading, and ends in bust, with procyclical liquidation of excess capacity and debt causing price deflation, unemployment, and economic stagnation. The result can be a deep depression.In 2000, the imbalance was America’s large current-account deficit: the world’s largest economy was borrowing heavily on international capital markets, rather than lending, as one might expect. According to then-Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke, the problem was that countries running large surpluses were buying so many US Treasuries that they were negating the Fed’s monetary-policy efforts. But, as Claudio Borio, Hyun Shin, and others have pointed out, excessive off-balance-sheet and offshore lending by US and European banks also added procyclical pressure.As a result, risk-taking and leverage grew, facilitated by inadequate regulation, culminating in the global financial crisis of 2008. To prevent asset bubbles from collapsing and buy time for more sustainable policy fixes, advanced-country central banks implemented massive monetary easing and cut interest rates to zero. Unfortunately, policymakers in most countries wasted the time they were given; moreover, so-called quantitative easing had far-reaching spillover effects.Within China, a second displacement occurred: the government implemented a ¥4 trillion ($680 billion) stimulus package in November 2008 to offset weak demand in its major export markets. While the Chinese authorities had the right idea, two of the policy’s outcomes have complicated the reform prcoess today.First, instead of reducing excess capacity and encouraging a structural shift to higher-productivity activities, the authorities’ investment-led strategy increased manufacturing capacity further, along with excess capacity in global commodity production.Second, the stimulus was funded by a debt binge, especially among state-owned enterprises (SOEs) and local governments. The private sector, too, built up debt, with its limited access to equity capital driving firms to the shadow banking sector. The result is a debt overhang of 282% of GDP.In short, China now faces the same debt-deflation challenge that much of the rest of the world must address. The question, of course, is how. Some argue that the answer is more of the same: continued monetary easing and additional fiscal stimulus. Accumulating more debt (at lower interest rates) can indeed buy time for economic restructuring. But it will merely make matters worse if politicians do not use the time to implement effective reforms.There is no politically painless way out of the debt trap. Indeed, the first step in that process is to face up to losses, both in accounting and in real terms. In the short run, even efforts to spur technological progress and innovation, which might generate recovery through new profits, are likely to have a negative overall impact on employment, owing to the creative destruction of obsolete industries. Recognizing this, some argue that the way to force reform is to allow interest rates to reflect credit risks.For China, whose net international investment position at the end of last year was a surplus of $1.8 trillion , or 17% of GDP, it will be possible to implement internal debt restructuring through debt/equity swaps at the project level. Far-reaching governance and structural reforms in the state and private sectors should follow.According to the Chinese Academy of Social Sciences, the central and local governments’ net assets amounted to ¥93 trillion, or 164% of GDP, at the end of 2013. Because SOEs and local governments accounted for more than half of the credit issued through the banking system, proper debt restructuring of state-owned assets would strengthen the projects they were funding, by allowing private or professional management teams to improve overall returns.Such reforms are crucial, because, ultimately, escaping the debt-deflation trap will require China to rejuvenate total factor productivity – an effort that the private sector is better equipped to lead. As the Scandinavian experience has shown, state ownership need not be an obstacle to productivity growth, provided that public assets are professionally and transparently managed, for example, by placing them in the portfolios of pension funds.The advanced countries have fallen into the debt-deflation trap because they were unwilling to accept the political pain of real-sector restructuring, relying instead on financial engineering and loose monetary and fiscal policies. Here, China’s one-party system provides a clear advantage: the country’s leaders can take politically painful decisions without worrying about the next election. One hopes that they do.
.....